Consumer Choice and Utility

What you’ll learn to do: describe the concept of utility and explain how consumers spend in order to maximize utility

This is a photograph of students at their outdoor college graduation ceremony.

Figure 1. Investment Choices. Higher education is generally viewed as a good investment, if one can afford it, regardless of the state of the economy. (Credit: modification of work by Jason Bache/Flickr Creative Commons)

Microeconomics seeks to understand the behavior of individual economic agents such as individuals and businesses. Economists believe that we can analyze individuals’ decisions, such as what goods and services to buy, as choices we make within certain budget constraints. Generally, consumers are trying to get the most for their limited budget. In economic terms they are trying to maximize total utility, or satisfaction, given their budget constraint.

Everyone has their own personal tastes and preferences. The French say: Chacun à son goût, or “Each to his own taste.” An old Latin saying states, De gustibus non est disputandum or “There’s no disputing about taste.” If people base their decisions on their own tastes and personal preferences, however, then how can economists hope to analyze the choices consumers make?

An economic explanation for why people make different choices begins with accepting the proverbial wisdom that tastes are a matter of personal preference. However, economists also believe that the choices people make are influenced by their incomes, by the prices of goods and services they consume, and by factors like where they live.

This section introduces the economic theory of how consumers make choices about what goods and services to buy with their limited income. If you look at Facebook for five fewer minutes a day, will you really be more productive? Is it worth it to clock into work ten minutes early, or would it be best to spend that time with your significant other? Is it worth it to spend five dollars on a dessert when you already feel a little bit full? In this section, you will examine choices made at the margin, or the decisions you make to do a little more or a little less of something.

Learning Objectives

  • Explain utility and its connection to consumer behavior
  • Calculate the total utility of a collection of goods and services

Consumer Choices

Information on the consumption choices of Americans is available from the Consumer Expenditure Survey carried out by the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. Figure 1 shows spending patterns for the average U.S. household. The first row shows income and, after taxes and personal savings are subtracted, it shows that, in 2015, the average U.S. household spent $48,109 on consumption. The table then breaks down consumption into various categories. The average U.S. household spent roughly one-third of its consumption on shelter and other housing expenses, another one-third on food and vehicle expenses, and the rest on a variety of items, as shown. These patterns will vary for specific households by differing levels of family income, by geography, and by preferences.

Table 1. U.S. Consumption Choices in 2015 (Source: http://www.bls.gov/cex/csxann13.pdf)
Average Household Income before Taxes $62,481
Average Annual Expenditures $48.109
Food at home $3,264
Food away from home $2,505
Housing $16,557
Apparel and services $1,700
Transportation $7,677
Healthcare $3,157
Entertainment $2,504
Education $1,074
Personal insurance and pensions $5,357
All else: alcohol, tobacco, reading, personal care, cash contributions, miscellaneous $3,356

Consumer Choice and Utility

When economists talk about consumer choice, what they are referring to is the combination of goods and services a consumer purchases. To understand how a household will make its choices, economists look at what consumers can afford, as shown in a budget constraint (or budget line), and the total utility or satisfaction derived from those choices. When we graph a budget constraint, the quantity of one good is on the horizontal axis and the quantity of the other good on the vertical axis. The budget constraint line shows the various combinations of two goods that are affordable given a specific budget (or level of consumer income).

Watch It

Watch the selected clip from this video to review budget constraints. The budget constraint graph shows the various combinations of goods (like coffee and pizza) that you can afford at any given price. We’ll finish the second portion of the video later in the module.

Consider José’s situation. José likes to collect T-shirts and watch movies. In Figure 1 we show the quantity of T-shirts on the horizontal axis while we show the quantity of movies on the vertical axis. If José had unlimited income or goods were free, then he could consume without limit. However, José, like all of us, faces a budget constraint. José has a total of $56 to spend. The price of T-shirts is $14 and the price of movies is $7. Notice that the vertical intercept of the budget constraint line is at eight movies and zero T-shirts ($56/$7=8). The horizontal intercept of the budget constraint is four, where José spends of all of his money on T-shirts and no movies ($56/14=4). The slope of the budget constraint line is rise/run or –8/4=–2. The specific choices along the budget constraint line show the combinations of affordable T-shirts and movies.

The points on the graph show how a budget is affected by spending choices. Spending more money at the movies (y-axis) means that Jose' has less money to spend on T-shirts (x-axis).

Figure 1. A Choice between Consumption Goods. José has income of $56. Movies cost $7 and T-shirts cost $14. The points on the budget constraint line show the combinations of affordable movies and T-shirts.

Utility is the term economists use to describe the satisfaction or happiness a person gets from consuming a good or service. José obtains utility from consuming T-shirts and consuming movies. Like all consumers, we assume José wishes to choose the combination of T-shirts and movies that will provide him with the greatest total utility

Let’s begin with an assumption, which we will discuss in more detail later, that José can measure his own utility with something called utils. (It is important to note that you cannot make comparisons between the utils of individuals. If one person gets 20 utils from a cup of coffee and another gets 10 utils, this does not mean than the first person gets more enjoyment from the coffee than the other or that they enjoy the coffee twice as much. The reason why is that utils are subjective to an individual. The way one person measures utils is not the same as the way someone else does.)

Table 2. Total Utility
T-Shirts (Quantity) Total Utility Movies (Quantity) Total Utility
1 22 1 16
2 43 2 31
3 63 3 45
4 81 4 58
5 97 5 70
6 111 6 81
7 123 7 91
8 133 8 100

Table 2 shows how José’s utility is connected with his T-shirt or movie consumption. The first column of the table shows the quantity of T-shirts consumed. The second column shows the total utility, or total amount of satisfaction, that José receives from consuming that number of T-shirts. The typical pattern of total utility, shown in this example, is that consuming additional units of a good leads to greater total utility, but at a decreasing rate. We can see this in Figure 2.

Graph showing a curved upward-sloping line for total utility

Figure 2. Total Utility Curve. This is a typical total utility curve showing an increase in total utility as consumption of a good increases, though at a decreasing rate.

The rest of Table 2 shows the utility José would obtain from attending different quantities of movies. Total utility follows the expected pattern: it increases as the number of movies that José watches rises. José can afford any combination of T-shirts and movies which is on his budget constraint. Which combination should he choose if he wishes to obtain the most utility possible? Table 3 looks at each point on the budget constraint in Figure 1, and adds up José’s total utility for each combination of T-shirts and movies.

Table 3. Finding the Choice with the Highest Utility
Point T-Shirts Movies Total Utility
P 4 0 81 + 0 = 81
Q 3 2 63 + 31 = 94
R 2 4 43 + 58 = 101
S 1 6 22 + 81 = 103
T 0 8 0 + 100 = 100

Calculating Total Utility

Let’s look at how José makes his decision in more detail.

Step 1. Observe that, at point Q in Figure 1 (for example), José consumes three T-shirts and two movies.

Step 2. Look at Table 2. You can see from the fourth row/second column that three T-shirts are worth 63 utils. Similarly, the second row/fifth column shows that two movies are worth 31 utils.

Step 3. From this information, you can calculate that point Q has a total utility of 94 (63 + 31).

Step 4. You can repeat the same calculations for each point on Table 3, in which the total utility numbers are shown in the last column.

For José, the highest total utility for all possible combinations of goods occurs at point S, with a total utility of 103 from consuming one T-shirt and six movies.

Try It

Try It

These questions allow you to get as much practice as you need, as you can click the link at the top of the first question (“Try another version of these questions”) to get a new set of questions. Practice until you feel comfortable doing the questions.

Glossary

budget constraint (or budget line):
shows the possible combinations of two goods that are affordable given a consumer’s limited income
total utility:
the satisfaction a consumer gets from consuming some quantity of a good or service; also, it’s the total satisfaction from consuming all the goods and services an individual purchases.
utility:
the term economists use to describe the satisfaction or happiness a person gets from consuming a good or service.