Efficiency
The familiar demand and supply diagram holds within it the concept of economic efficiency. One typical way that economists define efficiency is when it is impossible to improve the situation of one party without imposing a cost on another. Conversely, if a situation is inefficient, it becomes possible to benefit at least one party without imposing costs on others.
Efficiency in the demand and supply model has the same basic meaning: The economy is getting as much benefit as possible from its scarce resources and all the possible gains from trade have been achieved.
Efficiency is achieved when markets are in equilibrium. For each market, there is no shortage or surplus and the value of the goods produced to the buyers is the same as the cost of production to the sellers. For the entire economy, the optimal amount of each good and service is being produced and consumed and so we are using our scarce resources efficiently.
Prices
Prices are a critical element of the market mechanism, providing information to sellers and buyers to guide decision, adjusting to bring markets into equilibrium and promoting efficiency in the economy.
To illustrate the critical role of prices, let’s examine the case of price controls where the government sets the prices for goods and services rather than letting markets reach equilibrium and their adverse consequences.
Price Ceilings
Laws that government enacts to regulate prices are called Price controls. Price controls come in two flavors. A price ceiling keeps a price from rising above a certain level (the “ceiling”), while a price floor keeps a price from falling below a certain level (the “floor”). This section uses the demand and supply framework to analyze price ceilings. The next section discusses price floors.
In many markets for goods and services, demanders outnumber suppliers. Consumers, who are also potential voters, sometimes unite behind a political proposal to hold down a certain price. In some cities, such as Albany, renters have pressed political leaders to pass rent control laws, a price ceiling that usually works by stating that rents can be raised by only a certain maximum percentage each year.
Rent control becomes a politically hot topic when rents begin to rise rapidly. Everyone needs an affordable place to live. Perhaps a change in tastes makes a certain suburb or town a more popular place to live. Perhaps locally-based businesses expand, bringing higher incomes and more people into the area. Changes of this sort can cause a change in the demand for rental housing, as Fig. 1 illustrates. The original equilibrium (E0) lies at the intersection of supply curve S0 and demand curve D0, corresponding to an equilibrium price of $500 and an equilibrium quantity of 15,000 units of rental housing. The effect of greater income or a change in tastes is to shift the demand curve for rental housing to the right, as shown by the data in Table 1 and the shift from D0 to D1 on the graph. In this market, at the new equilibrium E1, the price of a rental unit would rise to $600 and the equilibrium quantity would increase to 17,000 units.
Price | Original Quantity Supplied | Original Quantity Demanded | New Quantity Demanded |
---|---|---|---|
$400 | 12,000 | 18,000 | 23,000 |
$500 | 15,000 | 15,000 | 19,000 |
$600 | 17,000 | 13,000 | 17,000 |
$700 | 19,000 | 11,000 | 15,000 |
$800 | 20,000 | 10,000 | 14,000 |
Suppose that a rent control law is passed to keep the price at the original equilibrium of $500 for a typical apartment. In Fig. 1, the horizontal line at the price of $500 shows the legally fixed maximum price set by the rent control law. However, the underlying forces that shifted the demand curve to the right are still there. At that price ($500), the quantity supplied remains at the same 15,000 rental units, but the quantity demanded is 19,000 rental units. In other words, the quantity demanded exceeds the quantity supplied, so there is a shortage of rental housing. One of the ironies of price ceilings is that while the price ceiling was intended to help renters, there are actually fewer apartments rented out under the price ceiling (15,000 rental units) than would be the case at the market rent of $600 (17,000 rental units).
Price ceilings do not simply benefit renters at the expense of landlords. Rather, some renters (or potential renters) lose their housing as landlords convert apartments to co-ops and condos. Even when the housing remains in the rental market, landlords tend to spend less on maintenance and on essentials like heating, cooling, hot water, and lighting. The first rule of economics is you do not get something for nothing—everything has an opportunity cost. So if renters get “cheaper” housing than the market requires, they tend to also end up with lower quality housing.
Price ceilings have been proposed for other products. For example, price ceilings to limit what producers can charge have been proposed in recent years for prescription drugs, doctor and hospital fees, the charges made by some automatic teller bank machines, and auto insurance rates. Price ceilings are enacted in an attempt to keep prices low for those who demand the product. But when the market price is not allowed to rise to the equilibrium level, quantity demanded exceeds quantity supplied, and thus a shortage occurs. Those who manage to purchase the product at the lower price given by the price ceiling will benefit, but sellers of the product will suffer, along with those who are not able to purchase the product at all. Quality is also likely to deteriorate.
Price Floors
A price floor is the lowest legal price that can be paid in markets for goods and services, labor, or financial capital. Perhaps the best-known example of a price floor is the minimum wage, which is based on the normative view that someone working full time ought to be able to afford a basic standard of living. The federal minimum wage at the end of 2014 was $7.25 per hour, which yields an income for a single person slightly higher than the poverty line. As the cost of living rises over time, the Congress periodically raises the federal minimum wage.
Price floors are sometimes called “price supports,” because they support a price by preventing it from falling below a certain level. Around the world, many countries have passed laws to create agricultural price supports. Farm prices and thus farm incomes fluctuate, sometimes widely. So even if, on average, farm incomes are adequate, some years they can be quite low. The purpose of price supports is to prevent these swings.
The most common way price supports work is that the government enters the market and buys up the product, adding to demand to keep prices higher than they otherwise would be. According to the Common Agricultural Policy reform passed in 2013, the European Union (EU) will spend about 60 billion euros per year, or 67 billion dollars per year, or roughly 38% of the EU budget, on price supports for Europe’s farmers from 2014 to 2020.
Fig. 2 illustrates the effects of a government program that assures a price above the equilibrium by focusing on the market for wheat in Europe. In the absence of government intervention, the price would adjust so that the quantity supplied would equal the quantity demanded at the equilibrium point E0, with price P0 and quantity Q0. However, policies to keep prices high for farmers keeps the price above what would have been the market equilibrium level—the price Pf shown by the dashed horizontal line in the diagram. The result is a quantity supplied in excess of the quantity demanded (Qd). When quantity supplied exceeds quantity demanded, a surplus exists.
The high-income areas of the world, including the United States, Europe, and Japan, are estimated to spend roughly $1 billion per day in supporting their farmers. If the government is willing to purchase the excess supply (or to provide payments for others to purchase it), then farmers will benefit from the price floor, but taxpayers and consumers of food will pay the costs. Numerous proposals have been offered for reducing farm subsidies. In many countries, however, political support for subsidies for farmers remains strong. Either because this is viewed by the population as supporting the traditional rural way of life or because of the lobbying power of the agro-business industry.
Neither price ceilings nor price floors cause demand or supply to change. We are assuming that for a given supply and demand for a product and therefore for a given market equilibrium, the government sets price controls that differ from the natural equilibrium.
Remember, changes in price do not cause demand or supply to change. Price ceilings and price floors can cause a different choice of quantity demanded along a demand curve, but they do not move the demand curve. Price controls can cause a different choice of quantity supplied along a supply curve, but they do not shift the supply curve.
Inefficiency of Price Floors and Price Ceilings
The imposition of a price floor or a price ceiling will prevent a market from adjusting to its equilibrium price and quantity, and thus will create an inefficient outcome.
Imagine the government controls the price of bread and implements a price ceiling ($2) lower than the natural equilibrium price ($4). This will result in a shortage of bread because there are fewer producers who can profitably supply bread at the new price and quantity supplied fall (1000 loaves) while quantity demanded increases (1500 loaves) because there are now more people willing to buy bread. So the question now is how do we distribute the 1000 loaves of bread to the 1500 buyers?
When prices are not allowed to allocate resources efficiently, we have to resort to other distribution schemes such as: ‘first come first serve’, rationing, favoritism, bribery, black market etc. These other distribution schemes are less efficient than the price mechanism and are very costly in terms of money but also time and efforts waisted. Imagined that you waited in line for 30 minutes and that the store runs out of bread before you could purchase one; the real price or opportunity cost of the bread now includes 30 minutes of your time and possibly even more because you now have to try another store. The black market would be another alternative to find bread as there will be people willing to remedy the shortage through illegal means, but the price on the black market is likely to be above the natural equilibrium price of $4.
Though not perfect, the market mechanism that relies on prices to guide sellers and buyers decisions and bring market into equilibrium is the most efficient system at our disposal.
Candela Citations
- Equilibrium slide. Authored by: S.Haci. Provided by: HCCS. Located at: https://s3-us-west-2.amazonaws.com/courses-images/wp-content/uploads/sites/1681/2017/08/03055356/equlibrium-efficiency.png. License: CC BY: Attribution
- Prices slide. Authored by: S. Haci. Provided by: HCCS. Located at: https://s3-us-west-2.amazonaws.com/courses-images/wp-content/uploads/sites/1681/2017/08/02161223/Role-of-price.png. License: CC BY: Attribution
- Principles of Economics - chapter 3. Authored by: Openstax. Provided by: Rice University. Located at: https://cnx.org/contents/aWGdK2jw@11.346:ylGUpUu9@6/Demand-Supply-and-Efficiency. License: CC BY: Attribution
- Principles of Economics - Ch 3. Authored by: Openstax. Provided by: Rice University. Located at: https://cnx.org/contents/aWGdK2jw@11.346:g7yTQfC4@11/Price-Ceilings-and-Price-Floor. License: CC BY: Attribution